Some reflections on Monetary Policy past, present and future − speech by Michael Saunders

Given at the Resolution Foundation
Published on 18 July 2022
Michael Saunders is near the end of his term on the committee responsible for setting interest rates. In this speech, he reflects on his experience. Then he looks at the effect of demographic changes on the jobs market and gives his view on interest rates.

Speech

This will be my final speech as an MPC member, because my second (and last) term as an external member of the Committee will end after the August meeting. I would like to thank the staff at the Bank and my colleagues on the MPC for their help and support over the last few years. My successor on the MPC will be Dr Swati Dhingra of the London School of Economics, to whom I offer my congratulations.

In this speech, I want to review some of the challenges faced by the MPC in recent years, and discuss the implications of dissenting votes among MPC members. Looking ahead, I will highlight the extent to which demographic trends may pose new challenges in coming years and outline my perspective on the near-term monetary policy outlook. I will make four main points.

  • In recent years, a series of adverse shocks – Brexit, Covid, the war in Ukraine and the current energy price surge – have significantly reduced potential growth and lifted inflation.
  • It is not surprising that MPC members sometimes disagree on the appropriate policy decision, especially when (as now) the economic outlook is challenging. Dissenting votes reflect differing views on the economic outlook and key risks, rather than disagreement over the aims of policy.
  • The UK economy is starting to face increasing challenges from demographic trends, which seem likely to cause persistently low workforce growth in coming years and (all else equal) limit potential growth to well below even the modest post-GFC pace.
  • Economic growth has slowed. But, with excess demand and low potential growth, some further monetary tightening remains likely in coming months in my view, to ensure that inflation returns to the 2% target on a sustained basis. It is especially important at present to lean against risks that recent trends in inflation expectations, underlying pay growth and firms’ pricing strategies become more firmly embedded.

Let me start by briefly looking back over my six years on the MPC. It began just after the Brexit referendum and the subsequent monetary policy easing, and has encompassed the implementation of Brexit, the pandemic and the energy price shock associated with Russia’s invasion of Ukraine. I want to highlight three important features of that period.

First, as in the period during and after the 2008/09 recession, the economy has been hit by a series of adverse shocks (Brexit, pandemic, energy price shock). Brexit and the pandemic hit demand, but they also have reduced potential output. This has occurred through reduced inward migration (hence lower population growth and labour supply), as well as adverse effects on productivity (through lower investment and, from Brexit, reduced trade openness). The pandemic has also caused a marked drop in workforce participation, mainly reflecting increased long-term sickness and early retirement, exacerbating the drop in labour supply.footnote [1] As a result, potential output growth has undershot even the meagre post-GFC trend. At the same time, the currency depreciation triggered by the Brexit vote lifted inflation in 2017-18, and the energy price shock is playing a big role in the ongoing rise in inflation. Hence, while inflation has been close to the 2% target on average in recent years, it has (as during 2010-16) been volatile around that target.footnote [2]

Figure 1. UK – Potential GDP (indexed to 1997 Q1 – 100)

Footnotes

  • Note: The forecast path is consistent with the May 2022 MPR. Sources: ONS and Bank of England.

Second, as in 2008/09 and just after the Brexit vote, the MPC has acted to provide prompt and effective support to the economy when most needed. In particular, the monetary policy easing in 2020 played an important role in helping to underpin confidence and to reduce the risk of a vicious circle of heightened risk aversion and tightening financial conditions.footnote [3] I supported that easing at the time and still believe it was the right decision. A failure to act then could have greatly exacerbated the pandemic’s long-term scarring effects in terms of unemployment and business failures. The MPC’s ability to provide effective support at times of heightened uncertainty and strains relies on the credibility of the UK’s monetary policy framework. The need to maintain – and strengthen – that credibility is an important consideration in the current setting of monetary policy.

Third, in order to be well placed to fulfil its remit against a backdrop of a relatively low neutral rate and sizeable economic shocks, the MPC has continued to develop its unconventional policy toolkit. Asset purchases were introduced in 2009, and have become a well-established policy tool, used again (promptly, and on a large scale) in 2020. As well as expanding QE, the process of reversing it has begun. Early this year, the MPC began passive unwind (ie not reinvesting maturing bonds), and initiated a programme of corporate bond sales. Work is underway at present on whether to sell gilts held by the APF and (if so) the design of such a program. In addition, the BoE and financial system established scope to set a negative Bank Rate, although this has not yet been used. The Term Funding Scheme (which developed from the Funding for Lending Scheme launched in 2012) evolved into the TFSME, with extra incentives for banks to lend to SMEs. All this helps to ensure the MPC’s toolkit is fit for purpose, and thereby contributes to the credibility of the MPC’s ability to return inflation to the 2% target.

Another feature of recent years, and especially the last year, is that there have quite often been dissenting votes on the MPC. Without replaying each decision, I want to offer some general thoughts on the implications of dissenting votes.

The way the MPC operates is that monetary policy decisions are made by majority vote, MPC members are individually accountable for their votes, and the votes of each member are publicly disclosed in the minutes that accompany each policy decision. An inevitable result of this framework is that there will sometimes be split votes, and that dissents will be publicly announced. Many central banks have broadly similar approaches, but some do not – some have a single decision-maker, decisions reached by consensus, or through private votes that are not publicly disclosed.

There is, of course, no level of dissent that is inherently too high or too low. Since the MPC began in mid-97, roughly 12½% (one in eight) of votes by MPC members have dissented from the majority (on either asset purchases or Bank Rate), with some variation over time. The MPC’s rate of dissenting votes is above that of the US Fed, but fairly similar to other central banks which disclose votes of individual policy board members.footnote [4]

Figure 2. Selected Countries – Per Cent of Central Bank Policy Votes That Dissent from Majority

Footnotes

  • Note: The chart shows the percentage of policy board members that cast a dissenting vote on the policy rate and/or asset purchases. Data start in January 2006 for Magyar Nemzeti Bank, March 2009 for Central Bank of Iceland and from January 1998 for the others. Sources: Bank of England, US Federal Reserve, Bank of Japan, Sveriges Riksbank, Czech National Bank, Magyar Nemzeti Bank and Central Bank of Iceland.

It is worth stressing that dissenting votes do not imply any disagreement among MPC members on the aims of monetary policy. The MPC’s remit is set by the government, and all MPC members sign up to it. Nor, I think, is there any substantial inherent difference among MPC members on the appropriate trade-offs between output and inflation when the economy is hit by shocks.footnote [5]

Rather, in my experience, policy differences among MPC members have tended to stem primarily from different assessments of the economy’s current position and the outlook, and of the importance of various risks around the outlook. For example, over the last year, I have put more weight on risks that, as Covid restrictions eased and activity recovered, the UK would face persistent domestic cost and capacity pressures and that maintaining our previous degree of stimulus would create a damaging rise in inflation expectations. But it is perhaps not surprising that other MPC members might disagree about such issues, especially when the economic outlook is challenging and uncertain (as recently and now). These decisions are often easier with the certainty of hindsight.

I acknowledge that there may be times when the public explanation of dissenting views can give the impression of a cacophony of disagreement.footnote [6]

Even so, I regard the MPC’s current system (individual votes that are publicly disclosed) as greatly superior to the main alternatives (single decision-maker, a Committee with votes in private but not publicly disclosed, or a consensus-based approach).footnote [7]

A key advantage of having a Monetary Policy Committee rather than a single decision- maker is that the combined insight and knowledge of a group of experts will usually exceed that of any individual. And genuine individual accountability of MPC members is probably only possible if votes are publicly disclosed. The current system also helps to ensure that uncertainties and disagreements over the economic outlook and risks (and hence the appropriate policy stance) are brought to the surface and discussed. Arguments get tested in debate among Committee members and external speeches. This is likely to improve the quality of policy decisions and economic forecasts. Moreover, credibility would be eroded if central bankers disagree in private on the appropriate policy stance but feel they should hide such disagreements to give a false public appearance of unanimity.

Some external commentary has suggested that dissenting votes are a useful lead guide to the MPC’s future policy decisions.footnote [8] However, dissenting votes are certainly not used as a deliberate policy signal of the overall Committee’s intentions, and it is wrong to assume that dissents reliably predict future policy decisions. Sometimes they do and sometimes they don’t.footnote [9] One reason for this is that economic developments may affect inflation prospects from one meeting to another, and MPC members will (as you would expect) react to this. In addition, the MPC’s votes are always over whether to adjust policy at the current meeting, and require a distinct choice (whether to change policy and, if so, by how much). Such votes may not fully reflect the extent of agreement (or disagreement) among MPC members on the economic outlook and future policy direction. Moreover, the votes may not fully reflect the extent to which each MPC member’s decision is finely balanced (or not). Sometimes, a policy decision can be quite closely balanced even if the votes appears overwhelmingly in favour of one outcome.

It may be possible for the MPC minutes to convey more sense of the areas of consensus and disagreement among Committee members, and the nuances around the votes of individual MPC members. But, unless the MPC detail the views of every individual member at each policy meeting (and I would not favour that), such subtleties may not always be apparent to outside commentators.

So what should external commentators look at to judge the outlook for monetary policy? I would suggest that you read the Monetary Policy Summary. For most people, that may be enough. For those who want to dig deeper, start with the MPC’s remit, and then read the MPC minutes, the Monetary Policy Report and speeches of MPC members. Perhaps above all else, focus on the economic data, the outlook and risks around the outlook – because that is what the MPC themselves will be doing.

A turning point in demographic trends

Turning to the outlook, the economy in coming years will continue to be affected by the major shocks of recent years (Brexit, Covid and energy prices). The UK economy will also face increasing challenges from demographic change, because population ageing appears likely to produce persistently low workforce growth.footnote [10] As a result, potential output growth is likely to be weak in coming years, with the path of potential output falling further below an extrapolation of the trend to end-2018 (and also further below its pre-GFC trend).

I want to spend some time discussing this issue, given the extent to which it is now beginning to shape the economic outlook.

The UK population has been ageing for some time, with the share of the adult (ie 16+) population who are aged 50 years or over up from 39% in 1993 to 48% this year. However, until quite recently, the effects of this on labour supply were quite modest. This is partly because the growth of the 16+ population has been quite strong (averaging 0.6% YoY over the last 40 years).footnote [11] Moreover, from 1980 until around 2007, population ageing had little effect either way on workforce participation among the 16+ population. In that period, population ageing reduced the share of the 16-19 age population, who typically have relatively low workforce participation (because many are in full-time education). There was little change in the 65+ share of the adult population, who have relatively low participation.footnote [12] The share in prime working years (ie 20-64) – who have relatively high participation – actually rose between 1980 and 2007.

Figure 3. UK – Per Cent of Adult Population Aged 20-64 Years, and Effects of Population Ageing on Participation

Footnotes

  • Sources: ONS and Bank of England.

Over the last 15 years or so, as the share of the population aged 65+ has risen, the adverse effects of ageing on participation have increased, pushing down on participation among the 16+ population by about 2½ pp since 2008 (ie 0.2 pp per year on average). However, over that period, these effects were offset by two other factors that have lifted participation.

  • Education attainment has risen markedly over the last 20-30 years, as the expansion of secondary and tertiary education in recent decades has rippled through the adult population. Workforce participation is markedly higher among people with higher education attainment (more so among women than men). This is probably because, on average, people with higher education attainment have relatively high pay and a wider range of job opportunities. To give a sense of the effects, over the period 2001-2021, the share of the 25-59 year age population with degree level education (who have high participation) rose from 17% to 41%, while the share with education below secondary level (who have relatively low participation) fell from 52% to 32%. As a result, the overall participation rate for this age group rose from 81.6% to 85.8%, despite little change in participation for people of a given education attainment (see figure 4). In all, rising education attainment has lifted aggregate participation among the 16+ population by just over 2pp since 2008 (just below 0.2pp per year).
  • Since 2009, the female State Pension Age (SPA) has risen in stages from 60 to 65 years, and both the male and female state pension ages rose from 65 to 66 years since 2018. The delayed availability of retirement incomes appears to have significantly lifted participation in the 60-70 year age groups, and together have added about 0.6pp to aggregate 16+ participation since 2009.footnote [13]

Figure 4. UK – Workforce Participation Rate and Education Attainment of People Aged 25-59 Years

Footnotes

  • Note: In 2022 Q1, the proportions of people in each category were as follows: Degree 42%, Higher education 8%, Secondary education 19%, GCSE 17%, Other 7% and Unknown 7%. Sources: ONS and Bank of England.

Figure 5 shows a decomposition of these effects in terms of their effects on workforce participation in the 16+ population since 2008.footnote [14] Over that period, the large downward effects on participation from population ageing were roughly balanced by upward effects from increasing education attainment and the rising SPA. Other than these effects, there was little like-for-like change in participation over the period 2008-19, with a small decline during 2008-11 that reversed by 2019 (and may have reflected cyclical factors).footnote [15] Since 2019, there has been a like-for-like drop in participation of nearly 1pp, which (as discussed) appears to largely reflect higher rates of long-term sickness and retirement, especially among people aged 50-64 years.

Figure 5. Decomposition of Changes in the Workforce Participation Rate (for the 16+ population) since 2008, and Simulation to 2032

Footnotes

  • Sources: ONS and Bank of England.

Given these participation trends, even with population ageing, UK workforce growth averaged 0.8% YoY over 2009-19, similar to the prior 10 years (0.9% YoY). The resilience of workforce growth limited the decline in UK potential output growth over that period, partly offsetting weakness in productivity growth.

Looking ahead, the latest ONS population projections suggest that the downwards effects on 16+ workforce participation from population ageing will expand to about 0.25pp per year in coming years. This is because the share of the prime working age population (20-64 years) will fall more quickly, with a faster rise in the share of the 65+ population (and especially the 80+ population).footnote [16]

Figure 6. UK – YoY Change in Population by Age Group

Footnotes

  • Note: Population data and projections are from the ONS. Projections published in January this year. Sources: ONS and Bank of England.

At the same time, the upwards effect on participation from rising higher education attainment will slow. The prior rise in secondary and tertiary education has worked its way through most of the working age population. And, barring a big new expansion of further education, it is unlikely that education attainment will rise as much in coming years as over the last 20-30 years. In addition, most of the planned increase in the SPA (and its effects on participation) has happened.footnote [17]

Combining these effects, and assuming that half the drop in like-for-like participation during the pandemic unwinds, a simple simulation implies that participation among the 16+ population will fall by about 1½ pp over the next 10 years (and fall further beyond then).footnote [18] Using the ONS’s population projections, this implies that the trend in workforce growth will average about 0.3% per year over the next 10 years, less than half the average pace of 2009-19 (0.8% YoY).

Figure 7. UK – Actual Workforce Path and Simulations, Indexed to 2008 = 100

Footnotes

  • Note: The central path assumes that half the drop in participation during the pandemic reverses over the next three years. The upper dotted line assumes all the drop in participation reverses, and the lower dotted line assumes none of it reverses. Sources: ONS and Bank of England.

There are, of course, uncertainties. If the drop in participation during the pandemic fully unwinds in coming years, then workforce growth will average about 0.4% YoY over the next 10 years. Conversely, if none of it unwinds, workforce growth will average about 0.25% YoY. The pace of inward migration is also uncertain, but it would have to rise significantly to alter the broad picture of relatively low workforce growth.footnote [19]

It is worth noting that, while the pandemic and Brexit have reduced labour supply significantly since end-2019, the prospect that demographic factors would reduce labour supply growth in this decade and the next existed before Covid.footnote [20] However, Brexit and Covid probably have reduced the likelihood that either inward migration or older age participation could rise enough to allow the UK to avoid these demographic constraints. Moreover, the recent shocks from Brexit, Covid and energy prices have absorbed so much focus that the UK’s demographic shift may (I suspect) have crept up somewhat unnoticed for many businesses, who otherwise might have implemented measures to adapt.

The paths for participation and the workforce in this simulation are fairly similar to the central forecast in the May MPR. In the MPR, that path for participation reflects a greater reversal of the pandemic-related decline, offset by adverse cyclical effects (as the rising output gap causes cyclical weakness in participation). The simulation in this speech does not explicitly allow for any cyclical effects on the future path of participation. Hence, to the extent that adverse cyclical effects do materialise, this analysis implies downside risks for participation and the workforce versus the May MPR forecast.

The UK is not alone in experiencing major demographic shifts, and the developed economies in aggregate have seen a slight decline in the 20-64 age population since 2014. But, the UK is rather unusual that this demographic shift comes through quite abruptly around now, with a fairly sudden slowdown in the growth of the 20-64 age population to around zero in coming years.footnote [21]

These demographic trends imply that, unless there is a sizeable improvement in productivity growth or a trend of rising working hours, the UK is likely to face persistently low potential economic growth in coming years. Figure 8 shows a decomposition of UK potential growth over recent decades and the next few years that is consistent with the May MPR. During 2010-19, potential growth averaged 1.7% YoY, reflecting trend productivity growth of 0.7% YoY and potential employment growth of 1.0% YoY (largely reflecting workforce growth, plus some effect from a falling NAIRU). For coming years, with trend productivity expected to be roughly stable, low workforce growth implies that potential growth will be only 1-1¼% YoY. Given the persistence of the UK’s demographic trends, potential growth may well remain low beyond the 3-year MPR forecast horizon.

Figure 8. UK – Decomposition of Potential GDP Growth

Footnotes

  • Note: Figures for 2022, 2023 and 2024 are based on the forecasts in the May 2022 MPR. Sources: ONS and Bank of England.

In theory, potential growth could outperform these projections if capital stock growth rises to substitute for low labour supply growth, and thereby lifts productivity growth. However, there is little sign of this at present. Business investment has been weak in recent yearsfootnote [22] and productivity growth has remained sluggish.footnote [23] Moreover, the positive effects on productivity from globalisation may be set to pause or unwind to an extent, if the pandemic and Russia’s invasion of Ukraine create a sort of tipping point away from globalisation and towards greater regionalisation of trade and investment flows.footnote [24] An understandable desire for greater resilience and stability of supply chains might come at the expense of higher costs and reduced productivity. Overall, I suspect that risks to potential growth in coming years are probably on the low side even of the MPR forecast, reflecting downside risks to both labour supply and potential productivity.

Of course, many of the factors affecting potential growth will also affect spending, and the impact on the balance between supply and demand could in theory go either way. A key challenge for monetary policy will be to judge the pace of potential growth, and hence to gauge whether the actual pace of growth is consistent with sustainable levels of capacity use (ie zero output gap). Rather than assume that GDP can regain something like its pre-pandemic trends, it probably will be especially important to monitor labour market conditions and domestic inflation pressures as guides to the medium-term inflation outlook.

Monetary Policy Outlook

The deterioration in potential output over recent years means that capacity pressures are widespread even with GDP only slightly above the pre-pandemic level. Much of the recent sharp rise in inflation reflects global cost pressures. But there also has been a marked rise in domestic cost and capacity pressures in recent quarters, with underlying pay growth and services inflation both above their target-consistent growth rates.

Figure 9. UK – Measures of Service Sector Inflation

Footnotes

  • Note: The first five series are year-on-year percentage changes. EOHO = Eat Out to Help Out. The Agents’ scores are ordinal series on a scale of -5 to 5, whereby a higher figure implies stronger price pressures. The latest figures are May 2022 for the CPI series, Q1 2022 for services producer prices, and Q2 2022 for the Agents’ scores. Sources: ONS and Bank of England.

As domestic capacity pressures have emerged and intensified, the MPC has tightened monetary policy since late last year.

Figure 10. UK – Longer-term Inflation Expectations

Footnotes

  • Note: The measure of household inflation expectations is the YouGov/Citigroup survey of inflation expectations for the next 5-10 years. The financial markets measure is the 5x5 RPI breakeven until
  • end-2019, 5x3 breakeven since then. The July 2022 data point represents the average of the daily 5x3 RPI breakevens until 14 July. Sources: ONS, YouGov/Citigroup and Bank of England.

There are signs that economic activity is slowing, as rising inflation erodes real incomes and spending. But this slowdown must be gauged against the backdrop that the economy early this year was in excess demand, potential growth is low, recruitment difficulties are elevated, and there is a sizeable backlog of unmet labour demand. Moreover, since the May MPR forecast, the government has announced further fiscal support measures.footnote [25] Longer-term inflation expectations, measured from financial markets and household surveys, have edged down recently, perhaps in response to weaker economic growth and monetary tightening (including expectations of further tightening). Nevertheless, longer-term inflation expectations remain relatively high compared to historic trends. Consistent with this, business surveys suggest that a sizeable net balance of firms expect to raise prices further, and firms’ pricing strategies do not appear to be constrained by the inflation target.

At its most recent policy meeting (in mid-June), the MPC said that “The pace, scale and timing of any further increases in Bank Rate will reflect the Committee’s assessment of the economic outlook and inflationary pressures. The Committee will be particularly alert to the potential for more persistent inflationary pressures.”

My own view is that further monetary tightening is likely, and indeed, as evident from my votes at the MPC’s recent policy meetings, my preference has been to tighten relatively quickly.

This partly reflects my view that risks are tilted on the side of a more persistent period of excess demand and domestic inflation pressures than implied by the most recent MPR forecast (published in early May). Despite the inflation-induced erosion of real incomes, I put more emphasis on risks that the backlog of unmet hiring needs and low labour supply will keep the labour market very tight. In turn, I expect that spending will be underpinned by low unemployment, the household and corporate savings accumulated during the pandemic, and the fiscal support measures announced in recent months. Moreover, unless restrained by tighter monetary policy, the relatively high level of longer-term inflation expectations implies that domestic cost growth and firms’ pricing strategies may remain above target-consistent rates even if capacity pressures ease to more normal levels.

Risk considerations also influence my policy views. In broad terms, the MPC has to balance the risks and costs of tightening “too much, too soon” versus “too little, too late”. In my view, the cost of the second outcome – not tightening promptly enough – would be relatively high at present. With excess demand and elevated inflation, “too little, too late” would increase the likelihood that recent trends in underlying pay growth, longer-term inflation expectations and firms’ pricing strategies become more firmly embedded. Such an outcome would increase the costs of returning inflation to target in coming years. And it could make it harder for the MPC to again provide policy support promptly and on a large scale if needed in the future. I believe it is important at present to lean strongly against those risks. Conversely, if the Committee tightens “too much, too soon” and then finds the economy and inflation pressures are much weaker than expected, the policy outlook could adjust (if needed) and inflation expectations would probably be better anchored than now.

The precise path of future monetary policy is, of course, inherently uncertain, because it will depend on future economic developments that cannot yet be foreseen. But I note that the BoE Market Participants survey and the Treasury’s survey of external forecasters both suggest that Bank Rate will rise to around 2% in the next year. Market pricing is even higher. Neither the external consensus nor the path of inflation breakevens implies that such a rate path will leave inflation below target over time. Without wishing to endorse those views too strongly, I do not regard such an outcome (ie that Bank Rate will have to rise to 2% or higher during the next year to return inflation to target) as implausible or unlikely. But, rather than focus on a precise forecast for Bank Rate over the next year, the key point is that the tightening cycle may (in my view) still have some way to go.

Figure 11. UK – Change in Bank Rate and Forward Rates in Prior and Current MPC Tightening Cycles

Footnotes

  • Note: The chart shows changes in Bank Rate and instantaneous forward rates compared to 3 months before the first MPC hike. Sources: Eikon from Refinitiv and Bank of England.

To be sure, a tightening cycle of more than 150bp would exceed prior MPC cycles (which typically saw Bank Rate rise by 100-150bp). Nevertheless, the starting point for Bank Rate in this cycle was unusually low, and the medium-term neutral level of interest rates may have risen over recent quarters.footnote [26] For example, unlike prior MPC tightening cycles, medium-term interest rate expectations (measured by instantaneous forward rates 2, 5 and 10 years ahead) have risen roughly in line with Bank Rate since late last year.footnote [27] By contrast, prior MPC tightening cycles saw little change in these forward rates, with yield curves flattening markedly.

This rise in medium-term rate expectations (which is also evident in the US and EA) may reflect a general shift away from more extreme versions of the secular stagnation view – ie that the outlook was for persistently sluggish demand relative to potential output, relatively flat wage and price Phillips curves, low inflation expectations, and continued weakness in domestic inflation pressures. Such factors, if sustained, could have implied a very low neutral interest rate and required policy to remain persistently accommodative relative to neutral. That scenario looks less likely now, given the rise in inflation expectations, evidence of excess demand, and the reawakening of the Phillips curve. As a result, market expectations of the neutral rate may well be higher than a year ago, while still well below the 20 years before the GFC (partly reflecting demographic trends). The shape of the yield curve implies that recent increases in Bank Rate may in part – not wholly, but partly – have simply kept pace with a rising neutral rate rather than actually close the gap with neutral.

I am not, of course, going to announce today how I will vote at the next (August) policy meeting. Our decisions will (as usual) be made, and announced, at the proper time.

Whichever way the economy and events develop, the MPC will, as always, remain focussed on returning inflation to the 2% target in a way that supports output and jobs.

The views expressed here are not necessarily those of the Bank of England or the Monetary Policy Committee. I would particularly like to thank Matt Swannell and Katie Taylor for their help in preparing this speech. I have received helpful comments from Andrew Bailey, Fabrizio Cadamagnani, Jonathan Haskel, Catherine L. Mann, Nick McLaren, Josh Martin, Huw Pill, Fergal Shortall and Silvana Tenreyro, for which I am most grateful.

References

Aksoy, Y, Basso, H, Grasl, T, Smith, R (2019), 'Demographic Structure and Macroeconomic Trends', American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, Vol 11(1), January 2019, pp 193-222.

De Albuquerque, P, Caiado, J, Pereira, A (2020), 'Population aging and inflation: evidence from panel cointegration', Journal of Applied Economics, Vol 23(1), pp 469-484.

Apel, M, Claussen, C, Lennartsdotter, P (2010), 'Picking the brains of MPC members', Sveriges Riksbank Working Paper Series, Sveriges Riksbank, Working paper No. 237.

Bernanke, B (2004), 'Remarks by Governor Ben S. Bernanke at the meetings of the American Economic Association', speech given at AEA, San Diego, California.

Bodnár, K, Nerlich, C (2022), ‘The macroeconomic and fiscal impact of population ageing’, ECB occasional paper series, ECB, No. 296 / June 2022.

Carney, M (2017), 'Lambda', speech given at the London School of Economics, London.

Cribb, J, Emmerson, C, O'Brien, L (2022), 'Labour market effects of the increase in the state pension age from 65 to 66', IFS working paper, IFS, Working paper W22/07.

Cribb, J, Emmerson, C, Tetlow, G (2013), 'Incentives, shocks or signals: labour supply effects of increasing the female state pension age in the UK', IFS working paper, IFS, Working paper W13/03.

Cribb, J, Emmerson, C, Tetlow, G (2014), 'Labour supply effects of increasing the female state pension age in the UK from age 60 to 62', IFS working paper, IFS, Working paper W14/19.

Ehrmann, M, Fratzscher, M (2005), 'How should central banks communicate?', ECB Working Paper Series, ECB, No. 557 / November 2005.

Firrell, A, Reinold, K (2020), 'Uncertainty and voting on the Bank of England’s Monetary Policy Committee', Staff working paper, Bank of England, Staff working paper no. 898.

Gerlach-Kristen, P (2004), 'Is the MPC's Voting Record Informative about Future UK Monetary Policy?', The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, Vol 106(2), pp 299-313.

Goodhart, C, Pradhan, M (2020), 'The great demographic reversal', Economic Affairs, Wiley Blackwell, Vol 40(3), pp 436-445.

Hoenig, T (2011), 'Monetary policy and the role of dissent', speech given at the Central Exchange, Kansas City.

IFS (2022), 'IFS response to government cost of living support package', published 26 May 2022 at Institute for Fiscal Studies.

Jansen, D J, Moessner, R (2016), 'Communicating dissent on monetary policy: Evidence from central bank minutes', DNB working paper, DNB, Working paper no. 512.

Juselius, M, Takáts, E (2018), 'The enduring link between demography and inflation', BIS working papers, BIS, No. 722.

Kim, J, Lee, J, Yoon, J (2014), 'The Impact of Demographic Changes on Inflation and the Macroeconomy', IMF working paper, IMF, Working paper WP/14/210.

King, M (2007), 'The MPC ten years on', lecture given to Society of Business Economists, London.

Lagarde, C (2022), 'A new global map: European resilience in a changing world', speech given at the Peterson Institute for International Economics, Washington D.C.

Liu, Y, Westelius, N (2016), 'The Impact of Demographics on Productivity and Inflation in Japan', IMF working paper, IMF, Working paper WP/16/237.

Nakhara, N (2001), 'The Japanese Economy and Monetary Policy in a Deflationary Environment', speech given at the Capital Markets Research Institute, Tokyo.

OBR (2022), ‘Fiscal Risks and Sustainability’, published 7 July 2022 at Office for Budget Responsibility.

Resolution Foundation (2022), 'Back on Target: Analysis of the Government’s additional cost of living support', published 27 May 2022 at Resolution Foundation.

Rachel, L, Smith, T (2015), ‘Secular drivers of the global real interest rate’, Staff working paper, Bank of England, Staff working paper no. 571.

Saunders, M (2018), 'Some effects of demographic change on the UK economy', speech given at the CBI Annual Economic Dinner 2018, Bath.

Sibert, A (2006), 'Central banking by committee', CEPR discussion paper, CEPR, No. 5626.

Vlieghe, J (2021), ‘Running out of room: revisiting the 3D perspective on low interest rates’, speech given at the London School of Economics, London.

  1. The ONS report that the number of people aged 16-64 who are out of the workforce due to long-term sickness and do not want a job has risen by 300K (0.7% of the 16-64 population) since Q4-2019.

  2. For example, in the MPC’s first ten years (from mid-97 to mid-07), inflation was within 1pp of the target in all but one month. Since the start of 2010, inflation has been more than 1pp away from the 2% target roughly half the time, with roughly equal periods on either side. In the period since I joined the MPC, CPI inflation has averaged 2.4% YoY and been within 1pp of the target in roughly two thirds of the months.

  3. During 2020, the MPC cut Bank Rate from 0.75% to 0.1%, announced £450bn in asset purchases and launched the TFSME, which provided cheap long-term funding for banks and incentives for banks to expand lending to SMEs.

  4. The year with the lowest share of BoE dissenting votes was 2004 (2%). So far this year, 31% of MPC votes have been dissenting votes, a pace which – if sustained – would exceed any prior year. Another measure is the share of central bank policy meetings at which there is one or more dissenting vote. This figure is close to 60% for the UK MPC, and is higher than for the other countries shown, which range from 32% for the Central Bank of Iceland and 36% for the Federal Reserve to 50% for the Bank of Japan (since 1998 for the BoE, Fed and BoJ, since 2009 for the Central Bank of Iceland). This measure is likely to be higher in policy boards with a relatively high number of voting members, and the UK MPC has more members (usually nine) than most of the other policy boards in this sample.

  5. In other words, it is unlikely that MPC members have significantly different lambdas, see Carney (2017).

  6. See Ehrmann and Fratzscher (2005). See also Jansen and Moessner (2016), who find that dissent among committee members increases the file size of minutes of policy meetings, but does not affect the readability of these minutes.

  7. See Nakahara (2001), Bernanke (2004), Sibert (2006), King (2007), Hoenig (2011), Apel, Claussen, and Lennartsdotter (2010), Jansen and Moessner (2016), and Firrell and Reinold (2020).

  8. See, for example, Gerlach-Kristen (2004).

  9. See King (2007).

  10. See Goodhart and Pradhan (2020) for a thorough analysis of demographic issues in the UK and globally, as well as Saunders (2018) and Bodnár and Nerlich (2022). Over time, demographic change also may affect the economy in other ways, including the neutral level of interest rates and public spending trends. See, for example, Rachel and Smith (2015), Aksoy, Basso, Grasl and Smith (2019), Vlieghe (2021), OBR (2022). Some research has suggested that population ageing tends to be associated with higher inflation, See eg Albuquerque, Caiado and Pereira (2020) and Juselius and Takáts (2018). Conversely, other research has found it is associated with lower inflation, see for example, Kim, Lee, and Yoon (2014) and Liu and Westelius (2016). Either way, I disagree and expect the MPC would be able to take appropriate action to achieve the 2% inflation target.

  11. The figures used here are from the latest ONS population estimates published on 25 June 2021 and the ONS population projections published 12 January 2022. Early results from the 2021 Census (released 28 June 2022) suggest that the UK population in 2021 was a little below these figures.

  12. Indeed, in the 10 years to 2007, the population aged 16-64 years rose by 8%, whereas the population aged 65+ years rose by 5% and so the 65+ share fell.

  13. See Appendix and Cribb et al (2013, 2014 and 2022). This estimate also allows for indirect effects of changes in the female SPA on male participation, as discussed in Cribb et al (2013).

  14. This is done through a shift-share analysis, with the 16+ population and workforce split by age, gender and education attainment (into 144 subgroups), such that aggregate participation can be broken down into contributions from each factor as well as behavioural change. The data are projected forward using education trends and ONS population projections.

  15. Other factors probably also affected participation among specific groups of the population since 2008, including changes in annuity rates, benefit legislation, social norms and health. Among the age groups, there was a modest rise in participation (allowing for education and effects from the SPA) for people aged 55-70 years, offset by lower participation among people aged 18-24 and women aged 45-55 years. But these effects appear to have been relatively small compared to those from ageing, education and changes to the SPA. Within the 16-64 age population, participation is less affected by population ageing and the effects of increased education have dominated. As a result, participation has risen by nearly 2pp since 2008.

  16. The ONS population projections imply that over the next 10 years, the adult population will rise by 0.6% per year on average, similar to the last 10 years. However, the population aged 16-64 years will rise by only 0.1% per year (compared to 0.3% per year over the last 10 years), and the prime working age population (20-64 years) will rise by just 0.04% per year (compared to 0.3% per year over the last years). Over the same period, the 65+ population will rise by 2% per year and the 80+ population will rise by 3% per year.

  17. There is one further rise in the SPA this decade (from 66 to 67 years, taking effect over 2026-28), with a further rise to 68 years scheduled for 2044-46.

  18. This implies a slight rise in participation among the 16-64 age population over the next 10 years.

  19. The ONS population projections used here assume net inward migration of 210,000 per year over the next 10 years, close to the recent pace (239,000 in the year to June 2021). Assuming UK migrants have a participation rate of 80% (matching the current rate), net inward migration would have to run at about 400,000 per year to keep workforce growth over the next 10 years at the 2009-19 pace.

  20. For example, the UK population projections released in the years before the pandemic also showed that the growth of the prime working age population (20-64 years) would slow sharply (to below 0.1% per year) in the first half of this decade, and remain low in this decade and the next. It makes little difference whether one considers prime working age to be 20-64 or 20-65 years.

  21. By contrast, the 20-64 age population has already been falling in Japan and Europe and, (using the UN projections) is forecast to continue to fall in coming years. In North America, the growth of the 20-64 age population has already slowed markedly but (using the UN projections) will not slow much further in the next few years.

  22. In real terms, business investment in Q1 this year was 9% below the level of H1-2016 (ie the Brexit referendum), the weakest in the G7, and compared to average growth of 13% in the other G7 countries. Recent UK business investment data may be revised up, but revisions would have to be very big to alter the point that investment growth has underperformed versus the G7 average in recent years.

  23. Output per hour has risen by an average of 0.7% YoY over the five years to Q1 this year, and a similar pace since Q4-19, close to the average since Q1-2009 and well below the 2.0% average during 1997Q2-2007Q2.

  24. See Lagarde (2022).

  25. See IFS (2022) and Resolution Foundation (2022).

  26. For a discussion of factors affecting the neutral level of interest rates, see box on pages 39-43 of the Inflation Report of August 2018, as well as Rachel and Smith (2015).

  27. It is conceivable that some of the rise in longer-term forward rates reflects expectations of QE unwind. However, if such expectations were to lift long yields without any rise in the neutral level of rates, one would expect shorter-term interest rate expectations to rise less steeply in order to achieve the same profile for the aggregate monetary stance. This has not been the case, with forward rates rising at both short and long maturities.